Skip navigation
Please use this identifier to cite or link to this item: http://arks.princeton.edu/ark:/88435/dsp01cn69m416s
Full metadata record
DC FieldValueLanguage
dc.contributor.advisorMorris, Stephenen_US
dc.contributor.authorSchonger, Martinen_US
dc.contributor.otherEconomics Departmenten_US
dc.date.accessioned2012-08-01T19:36:10Z-
dc.date.available2012-08-01T19:36:10Z-
dc.date.issued2012en_US
dc.identifier.urihttp://arks.princeton.edu/ark:/88435/dsp01cn69m416s-
dc.description.abstractRestricted transfers, or "Money follows people", are a policy instrument that combines public provision of private goods with competition between suppliers. Fee-for-service health care and school vouchers are examples. I find that restricted transfers have two unintended consequences, categorical inequality and competition attenuation, which threatens their promise to deliver the advantages of both government (categorical equality) and the market (competition). Most economists believe that competition (Smith, 1776; Hayek, 1968) drives innovation and thus productivity growth. Friedman (1955) famously argues that restricted transfers allow for higher quality at lower cost than government production. The intuition behind the two unintended consequences is as follows: the quality a consumer receives depends not only on her direct spending (price paid), but also on her acquisition activities. Examples of acquisition activities are travel, search, information gathering, and bargaining. Holding price constant, the more a consumer is willing to engage in acquisition activities, the higher quality she will receive. But, as Southworth (1945) points out, restricted transfers distort consumption. The consumer can, and will, partially undo that distortion by engaging in less acquisition activities compared to what she would do, if the direct spending had been the result of her own volition. Categorical inequality (ch. 1) occurs since for a normal good the poorer a consumer is, the more she is distorted, and thus the less she is willing to engage in acquisition, which undoes categorical equality. Competition attenuation (ch. 2) occurs as the consumption distortion implies that consumers are less willing to engage in acquisition activities than under ordinary circumstances. This means that suppliers operate in a market where consumers are less willing to switch suppliers for that requires acquisition activities. The result of chapter 1, the positive quality-income correlation, relies on quality being a normal good. Quality, unlike quantity, is merely ordinal. Normality is conventionally dened with respect to the demand function, i.e. linear budget sets. So the question arises what normality means when budget sets are not intrinsically linear. Chapter 3 untangles the denition of normality from linear budget sets, which allows chapter 4 to show that normality of a good is invariant to any order-preserving transformation of its dimension. Thus irrespective of any particular scaling of quality, and shape of the budget set, a consumer's preference is either normal in quality or not.en_US
dc.language.isoenen_US
dc.publisherPrinceton, NJ : Princeton Universityen_US
dc.relation.isformatofThe Mudd Manuscript Library retains one bound copy of each dissertation. Search for these copies in the <a href=http://catalog.princeton.edu> library's main catalog </a>en_US
dc.subjectcompetition attenuationen_US
dc.subjectimperfect competitionen_US
dc.subjectnormal goodsen_US
dc.subjectquality discriminationen_US
dc.subjectrestricted transfersen_US
dc.subjectvouchersen_US
dc.subject.classificationEconomicsen_US
dc.titleVouchers, Equality and Competitionen_US
dc.typeAcademic dissertations (Ph.D.)en_US
pu.projectgrantnumber690-2143en_US
Appears in Collections:Economics

Files in This Item:
File Description SizeFormat 
Schonger_princeton_0181D_10256.pdf845.4 kBAdobe PDFView/Download


Items in Dataspace are protected by copyright, with all rights reserved, unless otherwise indicated.